This study examines the growing applicability of signaling theory in understanding the US higher
education market’s structural challenges. Analyzing current trends through the signaling lens
reveals how credential inflation, workforce misalignment, and financial unsustainability stem
from education’s dual function as human capital investment and positional good. With public
trust declining, alternatives proliferating, and policy debates intensifying, institutions face
pressure to demonstrate authentic value beyond mere signaling. Empirical evidence suggests
20-80% of education’s wage premium may derive from signaling rather than skill acquisition,
creating systemic inefficiencies. Strategic responses emphasizing verifiable learning outcomes,
innovative credentialing, and outcomes transparency offer pathways to rebalance the
signaling-human capital equilibrium.
- INTRODUCTION: The Signaling Paradox in Higher Education
The US higher education system stands at an inflection point characterized by unprecedented
financial pressures, eroding public confidence, and fundamental questions about value
proposition. Trust in higher education has steadily declined, with only 47% of Americans
considering college worthwhile without loans—dropping to 22% when loans are involved (Higher
Education Inquirer, 2025). This crisis of confidence coincides with market consolidation
(over 40 college closures since 2020) and policy turbulence including endowment tax
proposals, research funding cuts, and DEI compliance pressures(Donovan et al., 2023). These
forces demand reassessment of higher education’s economic and social functions.
Signaling theory, revitalized by Bryan Caplan’s seminal work, posits that education
primarily functions as a costly screen for pre-existing traits (intelligence,
conscientiousness, conformity) rather than primarily developing human capital (Caplan,
2018). This study synthesizes empirical evidence and current market trends to argue that
signaling dynamics: (i) explain credential inflation and degree proliferation, (ii)
intensify under financial and competitive pressures, (iii) create systemic inefficiencies
requiring strategic rebalancing, and (iv) offer frameworks for innovating beyond traditional
models.
-
Theoretical Framework: Human Capital vs. Signaling Theories
2.1 Core Conceptual Distinctions
The human capital model views education as productivity-enhancing investment where
knowledge/skill acquisition explains wage premiums. Signaling theory contends education
primarily certifies innate abilities through persistence in demanding systems, with minimal
skill transfer (Ehrmantraut et al., 2020). Economist Kenneth Arrow’s formulation captures this
distinction: “Higher education contributes in no way to superior economic performance; it
increases neither cognition nor socialization. Instead, it serves as a screening device”
(Mincer, 1974).
Table 1: Contrasting Theoretical Foundations
Dimension
|
Human Capital Theory
|
Signaling Theory
|
Primary economic function
|
Productivity enhancement
|
Information revelation
|
Social returns
|
High (skilled workforce)
|
Low (positional competition)
|
Policy prescription
|
Public subsidy justified
|
Reduce public funding
|
Credential value
|
Content-dependent
|
Relative scarcity-dependent
|
Skill development
|
Central mechanism
|
Incidental byproduct
|
2.2 Empirical Evidence for Signaling’s Prevalence
Multiple econometric approaches suggest 20-40% of higher education’s wage premium derives from
signaling, with Caplan arguing up to 80% in specific contexts (Caplan, 2018). Key evidence
includes:
- Ability bias persistence: When controlling for educational attainment,
higher intelligence correlates with higher income, suggesting pre-existing traits drive
outcomes.
- Curriculum-content disconnect: Minimal retention of subject-specific
knowledge (e.g., foreign languages, tax preparation) despite years of study.
- Credential inflation acceleration: Master’s degrees becoming
entry-level requirements despite unchanged job complexity.
The signaling model powerfully explains why employers value philosophy graduates for banking
roles and why community college graduates face wage penalties despite comparable course
content—the institution’s selectivity signals worker quality(Kaymak, 2025).
- Signaling Theory in Contemporary Market Dynamics
3.1 Financial Pressures and Signaling Arms Races
Institutions facing operating deficits (reported by 4 of 14 Big Ten universities in 2023)
(Higher Education Inquirer, 2025; Kaymak, 2025)and endowment threats (proposed excise tax
increases from 1.4% to 10%) increasingly rely on prestige competition.
This fuels costly
facilities races and administrative bloat as institutions signal quality through non-academic
attributes.
Simultaneously, students respond to labor market signaling demands by pursuing
advanced degrees—not primarily for skill development but as competitive differentiators(Darien
Rossiter & Belinda Tynan, 2023).
This creates a vicious cycle:
Policy uncertainty → Funding instability → Institutional prestige competition → Rising tuition →
Student debt accumulation → Demand for stronger signals → Credential inflation
The “some college, no credential” (SCNC) population ballooning to 36.8 million (+2.9% since
2021) (Araki & Kariya, 2022) represents partial signaling failures where students absorbed costs
without obtaining the credential signal.
3.2 Labor Market Misalignment and Alternative Pathways
Employer behavior increasingly validates signaling interpretations:
- Degree requirement abandonment: 41% of US organizations have dropped degree requirements
for certain roles.
- Alternative credential acceptance: 48% of employers view non-degree credentials as
viablesubstitutes.
- Skills-focused hiring: Apprenticeships grew 102% (317,000 to 640,000) in a decade,
particularly in healthcare and technical fields.
Table 2: Employer Signaling Preferences in Hiring
Signal Type
|
Traditional Manifestation
|
Emerging Alternatives
|
Cognitive ability
|
Selective college admission
|
Skills assessments, challenge projects
|
Persistence/compliance
|
Degree completion
|
Professional certifications, portfolio continuity
|
Specialized knowledge
|
Major declaration
|
Microcredentials, industry badges (e.g., Google Certificates)
|
Social conformity
|
Extracurricular involvement
|
Volunteering, community leadership
|
These shifts reflect rational employer adaptation to signaling noise and credential
inflation. The rise of “career-aligned academic programs” (Buban, 2017) represents
institutional recognition that signaling value must be supplemented with verifiable skill
application.
3.3 Equity Implications and Access Barriers
Signaling dynamics disproportionately impact underrepresented populations:
- Credential inflation penalties: As bachelor’s degrees become
commonplace, marginalized groups must invest more for equivalent signaling returns.
- Accessibility gaps: While 75% find apprenticeships appealing, only 29%
find them accessible due to geographic and informational barriers.
- Conformity signaling bias: Non-traditional pathways struggle to signal
equivalent employability despite comparable skill development.
Caplan notes the regressive nature of signaling competition: “You must dwell on the
opportunities the poor have lost because of credential inflation. When most Americans didn’t
finish high school, dropouts faced little stigma... The stigma is now severe”(Gallice &
Grillo, 2018). This creates a positional goods trap where education functions less as
opportunity elevator than exclusionary gatekeeper.
-
Policy Implications: Recalibrating the Signaling-Human Capital Balance
4.1 The Subsidy Debate
Signaling theory fundamentally challenges higher education’s public subsidy rationale. If 80%
of returns are private signaling benefits, taxpayer funding constitutes regressive wealth
transfer subsidizing employer screening costs (Kjelland, 2008). This underpins proposals
like:
- Targeted subsidy reductions: Eliminating funding for programs with weak
employment outcomes.
- Human capital-weighted funding: Aligning subsidies with verifiable
skill development metrics.
- Signaling tax proposals: Taxing endowment income to capture positional
good rents.
However, abrupt defunding risks collateral damage to research, civic education, and
legitimate human capital development(D’Amato &Mookherjee, 2014; Kato et al., 2020). A more
nuanced approach would distinguish between pure signaling programs (e.g., general studies
with weak outcomes) and human capital-intensive programs (e.g., nursing,
engineering)(Botezat, 2016).
4.2 Accreditation and Accountability Reforms
Current quality assurance mechanisms often reinforce signaling by measuring inputs (faculty
credentials, library volumes) rather than learning outcomes. Reforms could:
- Shift emphasis toward competency validation: Western Kentucky
University’s data-driven enrollment management increased enrollment by 100+ students and
added $2.4 million in net tuition revenue through improved signaling of student success
likelihood.
- Promote transcript innovations: Granular skill inventories replacing
traditional grades.
- Develop signal calibration systems: Standardized skills assessment
across institutions.
The University of Wisconsin’s program array review—evaluating underenrolled programs for
consolidation or closure—exemplifies system-level signaling optimization (García-Aracil&
Albert, 2017). Such initiatives acknowledge that signaling efficiency requires strategic
program reduction.
-
Strategic Institutional Responses
Forward-looking institutions are leveraging signaling theory to enhance value proposition
through the four key approaches: (i) learning outcomes, (ii) credential value, (iii)
transparency, and (iv) differentiation(Stibbard, 1999; Yuki, 2009).
1. Signaling Authentic Learning Outcomes
a. Skills-based admissions: Degree programs accepting industry certifications as entry
requirements.
b. Learning gain documentation: Digital portfolios with verifiable project work.
c. Employer co-validated curricula: University at Austin’s administrative streamlining
(including offshore services) reduces costs while maintaining rigor.
2. Disaggregating Credential Value
a. Microcredential stacking: Graduate certificate enrollments increased nearly 10% in Spring
2024.
b. Competency hubs: Monetizing assets through innovation centers like Pennovation Works.
c. Accelerated degrees: Three-year bachelor’s programs with compressed schedules.
3. Transparency as Competitive Advantage
a. Outcome data publication: Employment rates and salary figures by program.
b. True cost calculators: Addressing application confusion cited by 30% of prospects.
c. AI-enabled guidance: Georgia State’s “Pounce” chatbot reduced summer melt by 22% through
clearer signaling.
4. Strategic Consolidation and Differentiation
a. Mission-focused program arrays: 50% of presidents acknowledge having too many programs
needing discontinuation.
b. Niche signaling: Private institutions like Villanova and Cabrini College merging while
preserving faith-based identities.
c. Public-private partnerships: Employer-funded tuition programs reducing student signaling
investment.
- Conclusion: Toward a Balanced Signaling Ecosystem
Signaling theory provides a powerful explanatory framework for understanding higher
education’s contemporary crises—from credential inflation and skills mismatches to equity
gaps and financial instability. Evidence suggests 20-80% of education’s private returns
derive from signaling rather than human capital development, creating systemic
inefficiencies requiring strategic intervention(Spence, 1973).
However, complete elimination of signalingremains neither feasible nor desirable(Collins,
2011). Credentialing provides valuable information efficiency in complex labor markets. The
challenge lies in rebalancing the signaling-human capital equilibrium through:
1. Democratizing signal access: Alternative pathways with equivalent labor market
recognition.
2. Containing signaling costs: Accelerated timelines and technological efficiencies.
3. Validating human capital: Verifiable skills documentation reducing employer reliance on
proxy signals.
4. Transparency regimes: Enabling rational signaling investment decisions.
As institutions navigate “a smaller market where more questions are being asked” (Viennet &
Pont, 2017), those acknowledging signaling’s role while demonstrating authentic value beyond
certification will thrive. Higher education’s future requires not signaling’s abolition but
its integration with verifiable human capital development—transforming the degree from
positional trophy into capability passport.
- REFERENCES:
- Araki, S., & Kariya, T. (2022). Credential Inflation and Decredentialization: Re-examining
the Mechanism of the Devaluation of Degrees. European Sociological Review, 38(6), 904–919.
https://doi.org/10.1093/esr/jcac004
- Botezat, A. (2016). Educational Poverty. NESET.
- Buban, J. (2017). Alternative Credentials Prior Learning 2.0. Online Learning Consortium.
- Caplan, B. (2018). The Case Against Education: Why the Education System Is a Waste of Time
and Money. Princeton University Press.
- Collins, R. (2011). Credential Inflation and the Future of Universities. International
Journal of Social Economics, 38(2), 12–46. https://doi.org/10.1108/01437721111110228
- D’Amato, M., &Mookherjee, D. (2014). Educational Signaling, Credit Constraints and
Inequality Dynamics [Discussion Paper]. Paris School of Economics.
- Darien Rossiter & Belinda Tynan. (2023). Designing & Implementing Micro-Credentials: A Guide
for Practitioners. Commonwealth of Learning.
- Donovan, K., Lu, W. J., & Schoellman, T. (2023). Labor Market Dynamics and Development. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 138(4), 2287–2325. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjad019
- Ehrmantraut, L., Pinger, P., & Stans, R. (2020). The Expected (Signaling) Value of Higher
Education (No. 8589). CESifo.
- Gallice, A., & Grillo, E. (2018). A Model of Educational Investments, Social Concerns and
Inequality (No. 405). Collegio Carlo Alberto.
- García-Aracil, A., & Albert, C. (2017). Signalling and Credentialism in Higher Education. In
Encyclopedia of International Higher Education Systems and Institutions (pp. 1–6). Springer.
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-017-9553-1_108
- Higher Education Inquirer. (2025). Degrees of Discontent: Credentialism, Inflation, and the
Global Education Crisis.
https://www.highereducationinquirer.org/2025/05/degrees-of-discontent-credentialism.html
- Kato, S., Galán-Muros, V., &Weko, T. (2020). The Emergence of Alternative Credentials (No.
216; OECD Education Working Papers). OECD. https://doi.org/10.1787/b741f39e-en
- Kaymak, B. (2025). Quantifying the Signaling Role of Education (Nos. 25–02). Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. https://doi.org/10.26509/frbc-wp-202502
- Kjelland, J. (2008). Economic Returns to Higher Education: Signaling v. Human Capital
Theory; An Analysis of Competing Theories. The Park Place Economist, 16(1).
- Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. NBER.
- Spence, M. (1973). Job Market Signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(3), 355–374.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1882010
- Stibbard, P. (1999). Labour Market Dynamics: A Global Survey of Statistical Activity.
International Labour Organization.
- Viennet, R., & Pont, B. (2017). Education Policy Implementation: A Literature Review and
Proposed Framework (No. 162; OECD Education Working Papers). OECD.
https://doi.org/10.1787/edu-wkp-2017-11-en
- Yuki, K. (2009). Education, Signaling, and Wage Inequality in a Dynamic Economy (No. 16982).
Munich Personal RePEc Archive. https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/16982/1/MPRA_paper_16982.pdf